While every effort has been made to follow citation style rules, there may be some discrepancies. Please refer to the appropriate style manual or other sources if you have any questions.
Select Citation Style Copy Citation Share to social media Give Feedback External Websites Thank you for your feedbackOur editors will review what you’ve submitted and determine whether to revise the article.
External Websites print Print Please select which sections you would like to print: verifiedCiteWhile every effort has been made to follow citation style rules, there may be some discrepancies. Please refer to the appropriate style manual or other sources if you have any questions.
Select Citation Style Copy Citation Share to social media External Websites Thank you for your feedbackOur editors will review what you’ve submitted and determine whether to revise the article.
External Websites Also known as: socialist law Written by Peter B. MaggsPeer and Sarah Pederson Professor of Law, University of Illinois, Champaign. Author of Changes in Soviet Law under Gorbachev. Co-author of The Soviet Economic System: A Legal Analysis, The.
Peter B. Maggs Fact-checked by The Editors of Encyclopaedia BritannicaEncyclopaedia Britannica's editors oversee subject areas in which they have extensive knowledge, whether from years of experience gained by working on that content or via study for an advanced degree. They write new content and verify and edit content received from contributors.
The Editors of Encyclopaedia Britannica Table of ContentsAsk the Chatbot a Question
Ask the Chatbot a Question
Public ownership of the means of production was a key feature that distinguished Soviet law from the law of most other dictatorial police states. The law distinguished between socialist property and individually owned private property. Socialist property included two subcategories—state property and collective, or cooperative, property—both of which were subject to virtually identical regimes of central economic planning. The system of private property included consumer goods, automobiles, houses, and agricultural implements for the very limited private farming that was allowed. The established property scheme formed the basis for propaganda claiming that Marx’s socialist ideals had been realized. It also facilitated the long-term maintenance of power and privilege. Because of the state’s monopoly on property, private institutions could not arise to challenge the regime. The government confiscated all houses of worship and made them available for use only to those religious organizations that posed no threat to the state. The state also owned all mass-media outlets.
From the time of the First Five-Year Plan of the late 1920s until the government’s collapse, the Soviet Union had a centrally planned economy, the main goal of which was to increase the military power of the state. Although there were limited market elements (e.g., consumers were free to choose the goods and services on which to spend their money), state enterprises became the predominant form of organization of production and distribution. General plans were refined into specific orders to these enterprises for production and distribution of goods and services. These orders in turn were implemented by contracts that state enterprises were required to conclude with one another. A set of state arbitration tribunals allocated responsibility when planned contracts were not fulfilled, and collective farms were forced to make and fulfill contracts for the delivery of most of their production to the state at beneath-local-market prices.
Soviet law recognized three distinct categories of employees: workers for state enterprises, employees of collective farms, and inmates in labour camps. Under the Labour Codes, employees at state enterprises enjoyed protection against arbitrary discipline or discharge. Except during and immediately after World War II, state-enterprise employees also had the right to change jobs. Restrictions on residence permits, however, made it difficult for workers to move to major urban centres in search of employment. Employees in state enterprises were represented by weak, party-controlled “pseudounions,” and there was no legally recognized right to strike. Peasants on collective farms were long denied the identity documents they needed for moving to urban areas, were not protected by the labour code, and did not possess (until 1965) even the legal right to representation by pseudounions. The peasants thus reverted to a legal position akin to the serfdom that had existed in Russia until the mid-19th century. Labour-camp inmates, who numbered in the millions, had essentially no enforceable legal rights.
Under Soviet law, status, rather than wealth or cash income, determined living standards. A large proportion of most Soviet citizens’ real income consisted of benefits directly allocated by the state. Secret laws and regulations provided for lavish benefits for the nomenklatura—the ruling elite at the national and local level. These persons received comfortable apartments, the use of state vacation facilities, automobiles with drivers, medical care at secret high-quality clinics, preferred admission of family members to universities, access to generally unavailable food and consumer goods at low prices, possibilities for travel abroad, and generous retirement pensions. However, they could lose these privileges at any time if they were suspected of disloyalty to the regime. Ordinary urban residents received housing from the state, but it was of lower quality and often required many years on waiting lists; they received free medical care, but it was of inferior quality; their children could receive free higher education, but only by performing well on entrance examinations or by bribing examiners; and their pensions were at a subsistence level. Collective-farm workers received free medical care but for most of the Soviet period had no right to state pensions. Labour-camp inmates often died of starvation or disease; at most they received what was necessary to keep them healthy enough to enable the camps to meet the production quotas assigned under the national economic plan.
Unlike market economies, which provide copyright and patent incentives to encourage creative efforts, the Soviet economy relied almost entirely on planned allocations of funds and tasks. Leaders realized that a strong scientific research infrastructure was an essential component of the militarized economy. Although resources were distributed to research institutes rather than to competing research proposals, the results were excellent in many areas of pure science and in some areas of applied science and engineering. Since no market other than the state market existed for inventions, however, areas neglected by planners (e.g., computers and electronics) lagged far behind. Publishing was monopolized by the state and subject to state planning; most works were produced by employees of state-controlled media or by authors working under contract to the state media. An effective censorship system ensured that works not meeting ideological criteria went unpublished.
Almost immediately after the communist seizure of power, Soviet family law was completely secularized. Divorce became possible by unilateral declaration of husband or wife, and women were free to obtain abortions. Under Stalin, highly conservative legislation made divorce more difficult, barred paternity suits, and outlawed most abortions. After his death, however, these restrictions were relaxed, and a pattern of family law was created that did not differ significantly from that found in western Europe.
From the revolution until the late 1930s, most of the repression of perceived enemies of the revolution was done largely outside the criminal-justice system; thereafter, it occurred mainly through the established judicial system. Under Stalin, numerous “counterrevolutionary” offenses carrying severe punishments were added to the criminal code. After the nationalization of private enterprises, engaging in private business became a serious offense. The criminal law was used to suppress religious groups that were not subservient to the state. Dissidents, particularly those who dared to publish their works abroad, were punished for the crime of “anti-Soviet agitation and propaganda.” Also, starting in the 1960s, dissidents were often punished for ordinary crimes under fabricated charges.
Criminal procedure was weighted heavily in favour of the state and party. Although the system generally followed the continental European model, which called for extensive preliminary investigation, the investigator in cases of serious crimes was not a judicial official, as in western Europe, but instead was an official of the procuracy, which also was in charge of prosecution. The investigator could hold a suspect without contact with legal counsel for months. From time to time, high party officials initiated campaigns against particular types of crimes, telling prosecutors whom to prosecute and forcing the courts to convict defendants. Starting in the late 1940s, there was severe pressure from the party hierarchy to secure a 100 percent conviction rate, with the result that thereafter there were almost no acquittals.
From the 1920s through the ’40s, world war, civil war, and purges greatly reduced the ranks of trained legal personnel. Judges and prosecutors usually had little or no legal training, and job turnover was high. Beginning in the 1950s, law schools began to produce substantial quantities of well-trained graduates, and by the 1970s virtually all legal posts were held by persons with law degrees. Because any deviation from party policy or failure to carry out party orders could ruin their careers, officers of the court tended to be highly subservient to the wishes of the state.